Caribbean small states | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Caribbean small states
Records
63
Source
Caribbean small states | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
5.8084249 1970
5.47119402 1971
4.72349861 1972
4.1848709 1973
7.28161282 1974
4.46109127 1975
4.59394731 1976
5.20890396 1977
5.23548913 1978
4.1401049 1979
3.45376963 1980
3.24914427 1981
2.50356109 1982
2.00483352 1983
2.63341498 1984
2.10749728 1985
2.22933146 1986
1.64132268 1987
1.48057502 1988
2.0765821 1989
2.09751406 1990
2.38221487 1991
2.22098091 1992
1.75924087 1993
1.84011009 1994
1.16895842 1995
1.35477565 1996
0.95331887 1997
0.70089378 1998
0.55211276 1999
0.57458763 2000
0.51026355 2001
0.37712249 2002
0.38432263 2003
0.65115484 2004
0.83013087 2005
0.9399372 2006
1.05746193 2007
0.8222867 2008
0.94172416 2009
1.6619857 2010
2.20547309 2011
2.18441103 2012
1.47502104 2013
0.83147359 2014
0.48454938 2015
1.35024829 2016
1.41539608 2017
0.40672323 2018
0.16218488 2019
0.22060088 2020
0.99062831 2021
2022
Caribbean small states | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Caribbean small states
Records
63
Source