Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.21478295 1970
0.11860892 1971
0.09480545 1972
0.20514306 1973
0.1635686 1974
0.07041905 1975
0.0939007 1976
0.07944728 1977
0.04994709 1978
0.04977317 1979
0.18008375 1980
0.1297125 1981
0.14287768 1982
0.12389843 1983
0.13687797 1984
0.15854966 1985
0.05625073 1986
0.04307046 1987
0.10165997 1988
0.10554912 1989
0.02844622 1990
0.01576268 1991
0.9210746 1992
0.50623529 1993
0.49532588 1994
0.41831055 1995
0.29356896 1996
0.20165884 1997
0.2993066 1998
0.38765277 1999
0.37580296 2000
0.26045338 2001
0.3089278 2002
0.22998332 2003
0.31622808 2004
0.48577108 2005
0.86798738 2006
1.23744303 2007
0.96054069 2008
0.67503292 2009
1.30079991 2010
1.33094831 2011
0.9938894 2012
0.82611279 2013
0.6782891 2014
0.58944107 2015
0.78668258 2016
0.82944727 2017
0.84958876 2018
0.74601656 2019
1.02574079 2020
2.30748624 2021
2022
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source