Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970 0.21478295
1971 0.11860892
1972 0.09480545
1973 0.20514306
1974 0.1635686
1975 0.07041905
1976 0.0939007
1977 0.07944728
1978 0.04994709
1979 0.04977317
1980 0.18008375
1981 0.1297125
1982 0.14287768
1983 0.12389843
1984 0.13687797
1985 0.15854966
1986 0.05625073
1987 0.04307046
1988 0.10165997
1989 0.10554912
1990 0.02844622
1991 0.01576268
1992 0.9210746
1993 0.50623529
1994 0.49532588
1995 0.41831055
1996 0.29356896
1997 0.20165884
1998 0.2993066
1999 0.38765277
2000 0.37580296
2001 0.26045338
2002 0.3089278
2003 0.22998332
2004 0.31622808
2005 0.48577108
2006 0.86798738
2007 1.23744303
2008 0.96054069
2009 0.67503292
2010 1.30079991
2011 1.33094831
2012 0.9938894
2013 0.82611279
2014 0.6782891
2015 0.58944107
2016 0.78668258
2017 0.82944727
2018 0.84958876
2019 0.74601656
2020 1.02574079
2021 2.30748624
2022
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source