Europe & Central Asia | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia
Records
63
Source
Europe & Central Asia | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.03018868 1970
0.01972094 1971
0.01737214 1972
0.0437352 1973
0.05639863 1974
0.01528758 1975
0.0271821 1976
0.02116447 1977
0.01124085 1978
0.01875211 1979
0.02392534 1980
0.01534811 1981
0.01542246 1982
0.01387904 1983
0.01133283 1984
0.01106194 1985
0.00444839 1986
0.00628479 1987
0.04275242 1988
0.04667327 1989
0.02062663 1990
0.0128506 1991
0.08403322 1992
0.05120971 1993
0.04367047 1994
0.03717851 1995
0.02392337 1996
0.0217964 1997
0.0227399 1998
0.02460689 1999
0.02982523 2000
0.01934965 2001
0.02275089 2002
0.01804137 2003
0.03262075 2004
0.05766757 2005
0.12140105 2006
0.17764165 2007
0.14767153 2008
0.09087477 2009
0.29148837 2010
0.35465941 2011
0.26805592 2012
0.23226763 2013
0.19088994 2014
0.11210246 2015
0.15822836 2016
0.20628537 2017
0.19501192 2018
0.12307273 2019
0.15373103 2020
0.37113775 2021
2022
Europe & Central Asia | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Europe & Central Asia
Records
63
Source