European Union | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
European Union
Records
63
Source
European Union | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970 0.02859191
1971 0.0196895
1972 0.01731589
1973 0.04301683
1974 0.05333992
1975 0.01384773
1976 0.02601862
1977 0.02022145
1978 0.01049387
1979 0.01853079
1980 0.02614469
1981 0.01646015
1982 0.01635813
1983 0.01502816
1984 0.01141166
1985 0.01119577
1986 0.00464565
1987 0.00689715
1988 0.05049769
1989 0.05337755
1990 0.02382093
1991 0.01542469
1992 0.01463233
1993 0.01065927
1994 0.01211206
1995 0.01310975
1996 0.00651845
1997 0.01027386
1998 0.00461973
1999 0.00433431
2000 0.00708597
2001 0.00358116
2002 0.00269635
2003 0.00270238
2004 0.01052779
2005 0.01704742
2006 0.04322842
2007 0.04778882
2008 0.02899552
2009 0.01522069
2010 0.15727649
2011 0.21499998
2012 0.14678503
2013 0.13263786
2014 0.12373918
2015 0.04289274
2016 0.07574207
2017 0.12845892
2018 0.11471578
2019 0.02613169
2020 0.02596697
2021 0.0732169
2022

European Union | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
European Union
Records
63
Source