High income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
High income
Records
63
Source
High income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.21698242 1970
0.14759409 1971
0.1278638 1972
0.22228424 1973
0.29710039 1974
0.16530524 1975
0.15594237 1976
0.15021834 1977
0.08266869 1978
0.12100422 1979
0.1378013 1980
0.09892801 1981
0.07738377 1982
0.07954451 1983
0.07198324 1984
0.07072033 1985
0.04708088 1986
0.05671506 1987
0.14974872 1988
0.11536508 1989
0.085118 1990
0.0615216 1991
0.05521282 1992
0.04064697 1993
0.05193993 1994
0.06273132 1995
0.05071713 1996
0.04953501 1997
0.0360071 1998
0.03422692 1999
0.0406823 2000
0.03309592 2001
0.02903493 2002
0.03256826 2003
0.06197077 2004
0.09083288 2005
0.17850078 2006
0.22373814 2007
0.2112537 2008
0.12221818 2009
0.30377365 2010
0.37404256 2011
0.25806178 2012
0.24813288 2013
0.19662406 2014
0.10233327 2015
0.12018299 2016
0.16871305 2017
0.1558183 2018
0.12355931 2019
0.15755776 2020
0.47448151 2021
2022

High income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
High income
Records
63
Source