IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IBRD only
Records
63
Source
IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970 0.6198198
1971 0.47453007
1972 0.41932653
1973 0.59202975
1974 0.98015456
1975 0.56732961
1976 0.58095212
1977 0.64512773
1978 0.42339742
1979 0.71831833
1980 1.14879956
1981 0.76052325
1982 0.62303366
1983 0.66991082
1984 0.38468225
1985 0.47180831
1986 0.37568434
1987 0.4768851
1988 0.81384394
1989 0.71835567
1990 0.50661054
1991 0.42276421
1992 0.55262281
1993 0.35688481
1994 0.37535137
1995 0.37602315
1996 0.31225561
1997 0.26803994
1998 0.29546571
1999 0.28631541
2000 0.27240609
2001 0.22681563
2002 0.24097713
2003 0.23931535
2004 0.40619062
2005 0.71769477
2006 1.15585819
2007 1.64648886
2008 1.60686766
2009 0.86592325
2010 1.61803793
2011 1.82889182
2012 0.99843387
2013 0.86325712
2014 0.58805772
2015 0.34699942
2016 0.40378936
2017 0.50402083
2018 0.46254334
2019 0.4074001
2020 0.43825551
2021 1.29201065
2022

IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)

Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IBRD only
Records
63
Source