IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IBRD only
Records
63
Source
IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.6198198 1970
0.47453007 1971
0.41932653 1972
0.59202975 1973
0.98015456 1974
0.56732961 1975
0.58095212 1976
0.64512773 1977
0.42339742 1978
0.71831833 1979
1.14879956 1980
0.76052325 1981
0.62303366 1982
0.66991082 1983
0.38468225 1984
0.47180831 1985
0.37568434 1986
0.4768851 1987
0.81384394 1988
0.71835567 1989
0.50661054 1990
0.42276421 1991
0.55262281 1992
0.35688481 1993
0.37535137 1994
0.37602315 1995
0.31225561 1996
0.26803994 1997
0.29546571 1998
0.28631541 1999
0.27240609 2000
0.22681563 2001
0.24097713 2002
0.23931535 2003
0.40619062 2004
0.71769477 2005
1.15585819 2006
1.64648886 2007
1.60686766 2008
0.86592325 2009
1.61803793 2010
1.82889182 2011
0.99843387 2012
0.86325712 2013
0.58805772 2014
0.34699942 2015
0.40378936 2016
0.50402083 2017
0.46254334 2018
0.4074001 2019
0.43825551 2020
1.29201065 2021
2022
IBRD only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IBRD only
Records
63
Source