IDA blend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA blend
Records
63
Source
IDA blend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.14026294 1970
0.1109437 1971
0.52894194 1972
1.22286641 1973
1.09993595 1974
0.54864589 1975
0.50908229 1976
0.51376492 1977
0.50660576 1978
0.65522109 1979
0.65619813 1980
0.25915018 1981
0.22327041 1982
0.35920427 1983
0.31810205 1984
0.3913431 1985
0.42527838 1986
0.60379776 1987
0.81873976 1988
0.76302094 1989
0.50813049 1990
0.72650637 1991
0.8048383 1992
0.58540143 1993
0.6201454 1994
0.34726888 1995
0.21043435 1996
0.11884228 1997
0.06662412 1998
0.10569081 1999
0.14549129 2000
0.07276495 2001
0.12784296 2002
0.13595517 2003
0.25144101 2004
0.2449723 2005
0.47752034 2006
0.45937743 2007
0.49372827 2008
0.52277951 2009
0.856815 2010
1.03540273 2011
0.77618178 2012
0.49893686 2013
0.37229398 2014
0.31843359 2015
0.50370695 2016
0.65568635 2017
0.66746426 2018
0.41459728 2019
0.53033471 2020
1.02191284 2021
2022
IDA blend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA blend
Records
63
Source