IDA & IBRD total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA & IBRD total
Records
63
Source
IDA & IBRD total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.72446295 1970
0.52690723 1971
0.49445416 1972
0.76136554 1973
1.09266039 1974
0.59121829 1975
0.60856289 1976
0.66106957 1977
0.43538621 1978
0.72369299 1979
1.10332144 1980
0.68859332 1981
0.56503617 1982
0.63297112 1983
0.39721477 1984
0.47137828 1985
0.39288263 1986
0.4952813 1987
0.83879172 1988
0.74911605 1989
0.52282801 1990
0.42738596 1991
0.54880852 1992
0.36061583 1993
0.38073874 1994
0.36509334 1995
0.30228701 1996
0.25620808 1997
0.2760273 1998
0.27315307 1999
0.26279875 2000
0.21942734 2001
0.23529965 2002
0.23127331 2003
0.39197964 2004
0.68387156 2005
1.11407666 2006
1.56580526 2007
1.53015778 2008
0.84793765 2009
1.56868464 2010
1.80459813 2011
1.01355826 2012
0.87016544 2013
0.59810257 2014
0.35877047 2015
0.42161665 2016
0.5289096 2017
0.48913086 2018
0.4195717 2019
0.46092562 2020
1.35757559 2021
2022
IDA & IBRD total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA & IBRD total
Records
63
Source