IDA only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA only
Records
63
Source
IDA only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970 2.24260539
1971 1.37053095
1972 1.34954932
1973 2.48295242
1974 2.42000223
1975 0.87719671
1976 1.05296016
1977 1.01214176
1978 0.52156312
1979 0.86357656
1980 0.94159158
1981 0.52090253
1982 0.37843528
1983 0.44550461
1984 0.65202412
1985 0.54705403
1986 0.5745356
1987 0.63612597
1988 1.25355463
1989 1.2889579
1990 0.79856926
1991 0.29643594
1992 0.30305869
1993 0.26924973
1994 0.29654926
1995 0.16673283
1996 0.20956916
1997 0.17549434
1998 0.15286629
1999 0.14115305
2000 0.17309215
2001 0.18629213
2002 0.21343421
2003 0.16098803
2004 0.24414445
2005 0.39518568
2006 0.84388593
2007 0.85225653
2008 0.84096253
2009 0.74537368
2010 1.11965968
2011 1.87631619
2012 1.6426408
2013 1.40710172
2014 1.06711135
2015 0.66422822
2016 0.7345135
2017 0.96950816
2018 0.95592399
2019 0.69842664
2020 0.89632128
2021 3.1454808
2022
IDA only | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA only
Records
63
Source