IDA total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA total
Records
63
Source
IDA total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1.28646835 1970
0.83429904 1971
0.971924 1972
1.94356686 1973
1.81496751 1974
0.73254086 1975
0.77653447 1976
0.76342184 1977
0.51436258 1978
0.7599097 1979
0.79276862 1980
0.35009294 1981
0.278577 1982
0.3954118 1983
0.48196556 1984
0.46849264 1985
0.5081424 1986
0.62243321 1987
1.06901446 1988
1.07642381 1989
0.68400204 1990
0.46766646 1991
0.51069536 1992
0.40028563 1993
0.4370011 1994
0.25784136 1995
0.21002682 1996
0.14550112 1997
0.10727927 1998
0.12803834 1999
0.16205856 2000
0.14102671 2001
0.17872612 2002
0.1507577 2003
0.24723446 2004
0.33051898 2005
0.67949338 2006
0.67799928 2007
0.6912828 2008
0.65487282 2009
1.01102643 2010
1.48367749 2011
1.21531971 2012
0.95946935 2013
0.72250446 2014
0.49733993 2015
0.63135694 2016
0.83787602 2017
0.82822752 2018
0.57380678 2019
0.74269699 2020
2.2477999 2021
2022
IDA total | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
IDA total
Records
63
Source