Korea, Rep. | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Republic of Korea
Records
63
Source
Korea, Rep. | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.04249942 1970
0.02865544 1971
0.02797912 1972
0.16574522 1973
0.18165493 1974
0.03657016 1975
0.03114574 1976
0.02293966 1977
0.01176618 1978
0.01911071 1979
0.04474813 1980
0.02004732 1981
0.0202437 1982
0.02301162 1983
0.01756678 1984
0.01510246 1985
0.01464784 1986
0.02514949 1987
0.06341503 1988
0.05475791 1989
0.02376284 1990
0.00364583 1991
0.00418983 1992
0.00119189 1993
0.00320897 1994
0.0101144 1995
0.00802268 1996
0.00766271 1997
0.01693242 1998
0.0101216 1999
0.00865487 2000
0.01032224 2001
0.01113364 2002
0.01296015 2003
0.00036708 2004
0.00157165 2005
0.00204711 2006
0.0024266 2007
0.003921 2008
0.00235547 2009
0.00478947 2010
0.00527297 2011
0.02088636 2012
0.00424846 2013
0.00229588 2014
0.00083147 2015
0.00115995 2016
0.00103511 2017
0.00030806 2018
0.08106271 2019
0.08435817 2020
0.00048329 2021
2022
Korea, Rep. | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Republic of Korea
Records
63
Source