Late-demographic dividend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Late-demographic dividend
Records
63
Source
Late-demographic dividend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.91516162 1970
0.6669886 1971
0.53408318 1972
0.73536888 1973
1.3911608 1974
0.81466456 1975
0.85049953 1976
0.95780735 1977
0.60275477 1978
0.7460353 1979
0.77113603 1980
0.68290351 1981
0.54416644 1982
0.5879102 1983
0.47162086 1984
0.4604802 1985
0.35274139 1986
0.41583287 1987
0.6882068 1988
0.57416497 1989
0.48559977 1990
0.44695049 1991
0.65903707 1992
0.43090635 1993
0.41517955 1994
0.4051467 1995
0.30862727 1996
0.28229973 1997
0.32465155 1998
0.34905068 1999
0.31523827 2000
0.24569454 2001
0.24098907 2002
0.24375043 2003
0.4252755 2004
0.73077347 2005
1.21632275 2006
1.73764586 2007
1.69142822 2008
0.85925083 2009
1.73130324 2010
1.95441717 2011
0.99450937 2012
0.8337362 2013
0.57545661 2014
0.33771846 2015
0.36942171 2016
0.46668311 2017
0.41196209 2018
0.35427164 2019
0.35928292 2020
1.08188188 2021
2022
Late-demographic dividend | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Late-demographic dividend
Records
63
Source