Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.58281247 1970
0.4886152 1971
0.49819972 1972
0.67667378 1973
0.94890769 1974
0.45095767 1975
0.47530369 1976
0.55056096 1977
0.40377659 1978
0.58393332 1979
0.6970913 1980
0.36121104 1981
0.49082677 1982
0.49073135 1983
0.47103605 1984
0.41098311 1985
0.23742288 1986
0.40492663 1987
1.30682453 1988
1.12642733 1989
0.74596317 1990
0.44163349 1991
0.35898589 1992
0.1925734 1993
0.20967932 1994
0.26092507 1995
0.22094603 1996
0.17882076 1997
0.18440647 1998
0.19665756 1999
0.198273 2000
0.17882032 2001
0.21041914 2002
0.22481365 2003
0.36804103 2004
0.67655613 2005
1.0319902 2006
1.40635692 2007
1.32167306 2008
0.71291011 2009
1.39462743 2010
1.63049746 2011
1.25233047 2012
1.10156868 2013
0.72513167 2014
0.49598298 2015
0.67869669 2016
0.78257813 2017
0.74628657 2018
0.53593907 2019
0.81059164 2020
2.87387978 2021
2022
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income)
Records
63
Source