Low & middle income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Low & middle income
Records
63
Source
Low & middle income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.51232079 1970
0.37726427 1971
0.37204179 1972
0.59040516 1973
0.9070977 1974
0.49642722 1975
0.4835599 1976
0.57065531 1977
0.35254525 1978
0.62489901 1979
1.03147614 1980
0.64253479 1981
0.52796811 1982
0.57801426 1983
0.34170535 1984
0.41439757 1985
0.33985765 1986
0.43079671 1987
0.77857533 1988
0.6688309 1989
0.44626353 1990
0.38893521 1991
0.52485272 1992
0.34453256 1993
0.33891787 1994
0.29750906 1995
0.25374401 1996
0.20545003 1997
0.2636996 1998
0.24952778 1999
0.2235135 2000
0.19500333 2001
0.21773471 2002
0.19658077 2003
0.30473368 2004
0.60460424 2005
0.94994755 2006
1.47117361 2007
1.49359019 2008
0.81452586 2009
1.47146221 2010
1.68368121 2011
0.91994419 2012
0.78940037 2013
0.52230247 2014
0.32735701 2015
0.3857055 2016
0.46217215 2017
0.42125481 2018
0.41644969 2019
0.43703572 2020
1.25427649 2021
2022
Low & middle income | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
Low & middle income
Records
63
Source