South Asia (IDA & IBRD) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
South Asia (IDA & IBRD)
Records
63
Source
South Asia (IDA & IBRD) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.1668602 1970
0.17433422 1971
0.17118161 1972
0.1532783 1973
0.18603417 1974
0.23815856 1975
0.36528917 1976
0.32820931 1977
0.21339403 1978
0.24067163 1979
0.2432833 1980
0.2257531 1981
0.2746686 1982
0.20892843 1983
0.20130702 1984
0.19829015 1985
0.19186356 1986
0.154264 1987
0.20289202 1988
0.25331422 1989
0.24166355 1990
0.18988119 1991
0.24429821 1992
0.2057805 1993
0.16014973 1994
0.16669828 1995
0.17633613 1996
0.16958264 1997
0.27530963 1998
0.20601048 1999
0.19028738 2000
0.20699963 2001
0.2026223 2002
0.18068711 2003
0.23186134 2004
0.64425712 2005
0.7932503 2006
1.35535586 2007
1.76084061 2008
0.74276256 2009
1.22574348 2010
1.14029162 2011
0.60773785 2012
0.6986253 2013
0.42097242 2014
0.22181568 2015
0.27366573 2016
0.35663068 2017
0.33428849 2018
0.50699073 2019
0.52858444 2020
1.02576315 2021
2022
South Asia (IDA & IBRD) | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
South Asia (IDA & IBRD)
Records
63
Source