World | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
World
Records
63
Source
World | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
0.26006555 1970
0.18019223 1971
0.16089512 1972
0.2719111 1973
0.38648648 1974
0.21587217 1975
0.20533212 1976
0.21167093 1977
0.12102725 1978
0.19441852 1979
0.27760133 1980
0.1914811 1981
0.15310053 1982
0.16443581 1983
0.11789332 1984
0.12716791 1985
0.08880271 1986
0.1070798 1987
0.24660091 1988
0.20905451 1989
0.14770282 1990
0.11296206 1991
0.12678129 1992
0.09166065 1993
0.09910686 1994
0.10148651 1995
0.08704441 1996
0.07911555 1997
0.07804412 1998
0.070624 1999
0.07350798 2000
0.06267293 2001
0.06316945 2002
0.06255659 2003
0.10837457 2004
0.19939854 2005
0.35574903 2006
0.53699732 2007
0.56130999 2008
0.31598005 2009
0.66636454 2010
0.80699507 2011
0.48526892 2012
0.43935216 2013
0.31192663 2014
0.18313161 2015
0.21469 2016
0.27655507 2017
0.25313503 2018
0.2319184 2019
0.26023246 2020
0.77097402 2021
2022
World | Mineral rents (% of GDP)
Mineral rents are the difference between the value of production for a stock of minerals at world prices and their total costs of production. Minerals included in the calculation are tin, gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, nickel, silver, bauxite, and phosphate. Development relevance: Accounting for the contribution of natural resources to economic output is important in building an analytical framework for sustainable development. In some countries earnings from natural resources, especially from fossil fuels and minerals, account for a sizable share of GDP, and much of these earnings come in the form of economic rents - revenues above the cost of extracting the resources. Natural resources give rise to economic rents because they are not produced. For produced goods and services competitive forces expand supply until economic profits are driven to zero, but natural resources in fixed supply often command returns well in excess of their cost of production. Rents from nonrenewable resources - fossil fuels and minerals - as well as rents from overharvesting of forests indicate the liquidation of a country's capital stock. When countries use such rents to support current consumption rather than to invest in new capital to replace what is being used up, they are, in effect, borrowing against their future. Statistical concept and methodology: The estimates of natural resources rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. This is done by estimating the price of units of specific commodities and subtracting estimates of average unit costs of extraction or harvesting costs. These unit rents are then multiplied by the physical quantities countries extract or harvest to determine the rents for each commodity as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).
Publisher
The World Bank
Origin
World
Records
63
Source